![]() |
Home
| Databases
| WorldLII
| Search
| Feedback
New Zealand Law Students Journal |
Last Updated: 14 January 2013
WRONGFULLY ‘RED’ OR ‘YELLOW-CARDED’ FROM A SPORT OR COMPETITION:
APPLYING THE RESTRAINT OF TRADE DOCTRINE TO HOLD SPORTS GOVERNING BODIES TO ACCOUNT
ROWAN ARMSTRONG∗
Introduction
Many sports can now be considered ‘big business’. Tagdell JA recognised this when his Honour stated that sports clubs are “conducting an entertainment business on a large scale”.1 With the commercialisation and commodification of sport becoming increasingly prevalent, there is an escalating desire for sports governing bodies to exercise greater control over the actions of players, clubs and other participants. Probably in many cases governing bodies see this as necessary to protect and enhance their credibility, to maximise potential revenues, and to further promote the sport in an environment of fierce competition. However when a governing body acts in a way to prevent or limit a participant’s ability to earn a living from a sport, by imposing an obligation going beyond that which is reasonably necessary, the act constitutes an unreasonable restraint of trade and is void. To cast an analogy with a rugby union referee, sports governing bodies may in some circumstances, if challenged, be wrongfully handing out ‘red’ or
‘yellow’ cards. In this professional age of sport it is therefore
desirable, if not necessary, for interested parties
to be aware of how they can
apply the restraint of trade doctrine to hold a sports governing body to
account.
The term ‘restraint of trade,’ has recently been thrust into the media spotlight after speculation that the conduct of a number of governing bodies may be in breach of the doctrine. Probably the best known situation was the stance taken by national cricket bodies (under the umbrella of the International Cricket Council (ICC)) who, in 2008, threatened to exclude those players involved in the ‘rebel’ Twenty20
Indian Cricket League (ICL) from playing all other ICC-sanctioned
∗ LLB (Hons)/BCom, University of Canterbury.
1 Australian Football League v Carlton Football Club Ltd
[1998] 2 VR 546, 548.
32 The New Zealand Law Students’ Journal
(2009) 2 NZLSJ
forms of cricket.2 If this position is maintained, it would
effectively put the players who participated in the rebel league out of full
time employment.
Another situation where athletes may invoke the doctrine is in response to a
governing body preventing them from competing in a sport
or competition after
committing a doping infringement. For example, the enforcement and legality of
the British Olympic Association’s
(BOA) byelaw 25 has come into question.
This stipulates that:
[a]ny person who has been found guilty of a doping offence... shall not
[subject to stipulated grounds of appeal] thereafter be eligible
for
consideration as a member of a Team Great Britain or be considered eligible by
the BOA to receive or to continue to benefit from
any accreditation as a member
of the Team Great Britain delegation for or in relation to any Olympic
Games...3
Christine Ohuruogu (the 2006 Commonwealth 400 metres champion), successfully
appealed the enforcement of this byelaw to be granted
permission to compete at
the 2008 Beijing Olympic Games.4 However British sprinter, Dwain
Chambers, who served a two year suspension for doping, was not so fortunate.
Chambers did not fall
within any of the stipulated grounds for appeal
prescribed by the byelaw and therefore the only realistic route for
him5 was to challenge its legality on the basis that it constituted
an unreasonable restraint of trade. Mackay J, in the English High Court,
refused
to grant Chambers an injunction to temporarily suspend the BOA’s byelaw in
the absence of a full hearing.6
2 See Part C (1) of this article, in particular commentary in footnotes n 89-108, for comprehensive analysis of this situation.
3 <http://www.olympics.org.uk/documents/Eligibility%20bye%20law%20(Final%20No
v%202004).pdf>. The stipulated grounds of appeal are contained in byelaw 25(6)(5).
4 The Daily Mail, ‘Christine Ohuruogu Cleared to Run in Olympics after Lifetime Ban
Drug is Lifted’(2008) Daily Mail Sport, <http://www.dailymail.co.uk/pages/live/articles/
sport/sport.html?in_article_id=496693&in_page_id=1771> at 29 January 2008.
5 The Guardian, ‘BOA Ready for Chambers Challenge’(2008) The Guardian Sport,
<http://sport.guardian.co.uk/athletics/story/ 0,,2262362,00.html> at 5 March 2008. Any
appeal to the Court of Arbitration for Sport was unlikely to have been heard before the
Beijing Olympics started on 8 August 2008.
6 Chambers v British Olympic Association [2008] EWHC 2028
(QB). MacKay J noted at [66] that “many people inside and outside the
sport, would see [this byelaw as unlawful].... In my judgment,
it would take a
much better case than the claimant presents to persuade me
Wrongfully ‘Red’ or ‘Yellow-Carded’
33
Aside from restrictions on participating in a sport or competition, there has
also been recent speculation that salary caps, as a
form of labour market
control, may constitute an unreasonable restraint of trade.7 This
matter has yet to be determined and one can only wait with interest until
inevitably an aggrieved sportsperson challenges a governing
body for not being
able to earn the amount that they deem themselves to be worth.
This article will further explore and expand on these situations, with an aim
to provide interested parties with a practical analysis
as to the scope and
circumstances in which a restraint of trade claim may ultimately succeed. As
the categories of restraint of
trade are “not exhausted and never
closed”8 it is simply not possible to foresee every situation
in which a challenge could successfully be brought. Nevertheless it is
fundamental
in this professional age of sport for interested parties to have an
appreciation of the principles and the established circumstances
in which the
doctrine may be called upon to challenge the authority of a
self-regulatory9 governing body. This article will significantly
analyse the Australian and English restraint of trade cases. As the doctrine is
premised
in the common law, these authorities hold a great deal of influence in
the New Zealand courts.
A. Restraint of Trade as a Mechanism for Challenge
It is important to emphasise from the outset that restraint of trade is
merely one mechanism available to hold a sports governing
body to account.
Judicial review,10 a contractual cause of action,11
interference
to overturn the status quo, that is to say, the validity of this byelaw at this stage and thereby compel his selection”.
7 For example see: M Beloff QC, ‘Gaming and Doping Continue to Threaten
Sport’(2007) The Telegraph Sport, <http://www.telegraph.co.uk/sport/main.jhtml ?xml=/ sport/2007/12/26/sodrug126.xml> at 25 December 2007. For further information see commentary below n 87.
8 G Treitel, The Law of Contract (9th ed, 1994), 413 in P Morris & G Little, ‘Challenging
Sports Bodies Determinations’ (1998) 17 Civil Justice Quarterly 128, 140.
9 J Black, ‘Constitutionalising Self-Regulation’ (1996) 59 Modern Law Review 24, 27. This
describes the situation of “a group of persons or bodies, acting together, performing a regulatory function in respect of themselves and others who accept their authority”.
10 R Armstrong, ‘The Whistle has Blown ... Game Over ... Or is it Really? Challenging the
Decisions of Sports Governing Bodies in New Zealand’ (2008) 14 Canterbury Law Review
65; J Caldwell, ‘Judicial Review of Sports Bodies in New
Zealand,’ 44 in E Toomey (ed),
with a person’s right to work,12 and specific legislation
such as the New Zealand Bill of Rights Act 199013 and the Commerce
Act 198614 may be applicable and even brought in conjunction with a
restraint of trade claim in an appropriate situation. Due to the intricacy
of
the restraint of trade doctrine though, this article will not elaborate on these
other bases of challenge.
Restraint of trade is an extremely flexible mechanism which is founded on the
public policy that no person should be unreasonably
restrained in the pursuit of
his or her trade or profession.15 As seen from the factual contexts
above, the common law doctrine is not limited to contractual restraints; it can
be used to challenge
a sports body’s rules, policies, practices and
disciplinary tribunal rulings. More broadly it is applicable to all restraints,
however imposed, and whether voluntary or involuntary.16
Another important feature of the doctrine is its accessibility. Although
historically case law has suggested that there must be a
contractual
relationship between the parties, in that the court will only decline to enforce
a contractual term,17 this no longer seems to be the
position.18
Keeping the Score: Essays in Law and Sport (2002).
11 Ibid.
12 See Nagle v Feilden [1966] 1 All ER 689; McInnes v Onslow-Fane [1978] 1 WLR 1520;
Hughes v Western Australian Cricket Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660, 703-704.
13 For example see: Stratford Racing Club Inc v Adlam [2008] NZCA 92, [59] (per Chambers
J).
14 Commerce Act 1986 s 7(1) provides that nothing in the Act limits or affects any rule of
law relating to restraint of trade not inconsistent with the provisions of the Act. Similarly the Australian Trade Practices Act 1974 s 4M(a) provides that the common law restraint of trade doctrine is to continue in effect ‘insofar as that law is capable of operating concurrently’ with the Act.
15 B Ward, ‘Fair Play: Professional Sport and Restraint of Trade’ (1985) 59 Law Institute
Journal 545.
16 Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 375.
17 See R v The Benchers of Lincoln's Inn [1825] EngR 814; (1825) 4 B & C 855; 107 ER 1277; Peter Watts
argued that the Court in Nagle v Feilden perverted the doctrine of restraint of trade, “which at most involves the court in declining to give its aid to certain types of contractual provision, into suggesting that powerful parties can be forced to offer work to someone” (P Watts, ‘The Tort of Refusing to Contract’ (2008) 14 New Zealand Business Law Quarterly 69). On this basis it could be argued that the restraint of trade doctrine is a
‘negative doctrine’ only, in that it should not be used to force sports bodies to give
sportspersons entry to the industry, nor impose positive obligations of reasonableness on sports bodies.
18 Nagle v Feilden [1966] 1 All ER 689; Buckley v Tutty
[1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353; Smellie J in
This was clearly illustrated in Stininato v Auckland Boxing
Association (Inc)19 where the claimant, a professional boxer,
was refused access to the sport. Despite the absence of a contract with the
governing body,
the Court was willing to apply the doctrine.
It is also not necessary to be a party to a challenged agreement to lodge a
restraint of trade claim. A third party can bring an action
if they are
unreasonably restrained by an agreement’s operation.20 It is
anticipated that third parties (notably sportspersons and coaches) will invoke
the doctrine more frequently in the future where
there is a fettering of
commercial freedom. For instance, one situation may be where there is a conflict
between a governing body’s
or team’s sponsorship, media or marketing
arrangements and the sportsperson’s personal arrangements.
The substantive remedies available to a successful litigant
on establishing an unreasonable restraint of trade can
be extremely
effective.21 Characteristically in the context of sporting
restraints, a declaration will be issued either pursuant to the court’s
inherent
jurisdiction or the Declaratory Judgments Act 1908 that the particular
clause, rule, term or decision is an unreasonable restraint
of trade, void, and
thus unenforceable. Lord Wilberforce in Eastham v Newcastle United Football
Club Ltd22 additionally noted that:
the court has jurisdiction to grant a declaratory judgment, not only against
the employer who is in contractual relationship with
the employee, but also
against the association of employers whose rules or regulations place an
unjustifiable restraint on his liberty
of
employment.23
Rugby Union Players’ Association Inc v Commerce Commission(No 2) [1997] 3 NZLR 301, 315 approved the principles set out in Foschini v Victoria Football League (unreported, Supreme Court of Victoria, 9868/82, Crockett J, 15 April 1983) where the Court noted that the correctness of the proposition that the doctrine is not limited to a contractual relationship “may now be considered to be beyond doubt”; Stratford Racing Club Inc v Adlam [2008] NZCA 92.
20 S Gardiner et al, Sports Law (3rd ed, 2006), 216.
21 Damages are rarely claimed in a restraint of trade action. Only when a contract exists
between the parties could damages be awarded: Nagle v Feilden [1966] 1 All ER 689.
23 Ibid 157.
However a declaration will not be issued as of right on an unreasonable restraint of trade being made out. The remedy is discretionary.24
Although it will be rare, the most likely reasons for a court in declining to
issue a declaration is if it would serve no useful purpose,
there is a delay in
bringing the claim, third parties would be prejudiced, or on the broad concept
of the ‘overall justice’
of the situation.25 Also in
conjunction with a declaratory judgment, a mandatory injunction will often be
sought to prevent the governing body from continuing
to apply the
restraint.26 Furthermore, if the restraint of trade is premised in a
contract, the New Zealand courts by virtue of the Illegal Contracts Act (ICA)
1970 have a wider jurisdiction than at common law27 to modify the
restraint provision. Section 8 ICA 1970 provides that the courts may delete an
objectionable provision and enforce the
amended contract, or modify the
provision so that it is in a form which would have been reasonable at the time
that the contract
was entered into and then give affect to the modified
contract. But where any deletion or modification would alter the bargain between
the parties in a way that it would be unreasonable to allow the contract to
stand, the court may decline to enforce the contract.28
B. The Legal Framework Applied by the Courts in Determining an Unreasonable Restraint of Trade
The conventional29 authoritative framework applied by the courts
on analysing whether there is an unreasonable restraint dates from the
19th
24 Declaratory Judgments Act 1908s 10; see also, Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547, 572 (per McCarthy J); Stininato v Auckland Boxing Association (Inc) [1978] 1 NZLR 1, 8 (per Richmond P) and 29 (per Cooke J); Stevenage Borough Football Club v Football League Ltd (1996) 9 Admin LR 109 where relief was refused.
25 See: Eastham v Newcastle United Football Club Ltd [1963] 3 All ER 139, 159; Stevenage
Borough Football Club v Football League Ltd (1996) 9 Admin LR 109.
26 For example see Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353.
27 J Burrows, J Finn & S Todd, Law of Contract in New Zealand (3rd ed, 2007), 434;
LexisNexis, The Laws of New Zealand: Contract, Part IX Illegal Contracts (2008), [233]-[237]. At common law, the courts could only sever objectionable parts in a contract where this could be done without destroying the contract.
28 J Burrows, J Finn & S Todd, Law of Contract in New Zealand (3rd ed, 2007), 434 – “the
word “may” in subsection (1) is to be read meaning “shall” so that the Court must choose one of the three statutory options of - enforcement of the restraint, declining to enforce it, or modifying it and enforcing it as modified.”
29 Note that in Stevenage Borough Footall Club v Football League Ltd (1996) 9 Admin LR 109
the Court held, in relation to a challenge on the sports body’s rules,
that the plaintiff was
century House of Lords decision Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and
Ammunition Co Ltd.30 Lord Macnaghten held that a restraining
practice would be deemed void unless it was justified that:
the restraint is reasonable – reasonable, that is, in reference to
the interests of the parties concerned and reasonable in reference to the
interests of the public, so framed and so guarded as to afford adequate
protection to the party in whose favour it is imposed, while at the same time it
is in no way injurious to the public.31 [Emphasis added].
As the doctrine is premised on public policy, it is difficult to ascribe
strict rules when analysing whether a situation should warrant
a finding that
the restraint is unreasonable. The court has significant discretion and will
typically perform a balancing act
based on a range of competing
subjective values.
1. Is there a restraint of trade?
A necessary preliminary point to consider is whether the matter in question
is actually a restraint of trade. If so, then
prima facie the
restraint will be void.32 The onus in establishing the restraint
rests with the party affected – the player, club or other participant
(also referred
to in this article as the claimant).33 It must be
shown that the obligation prevents or limits their ability to earn a living
through the sport.
(a) Is the claimant ‘in trade?’
It is irrelevant whether the sporting body in question is engaged in trade,
it is only necessary for a sportsperson to be so engaged.34 This
will clearly occur if the sportsperson is deemed to be a professional,
in
to establish that there was a restraint and that it did not operate reasonably in the
interests of the public. The first limb of Lord Macnaghten’s reasonableness test, (whether the restriction was in the interests of the parties) was omitted. This approach has not
been adopted in any other cases to date, but has not expressly been overruled.
30 [1894] UKLawRpAC 52; [1894] AC 535.
31 Ibid 565.
32 Ibid; applied in Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547, 555
and 569.
33 Hughes v Western Australian Cricket Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660, 702.
34 Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353.
that they receive payment from participation in a sport.35 However
it is not essential that their entire or even a substantial part of their income
derives from the sport. A sportsperson
will be considered a
professional if they are part-time.36
In previous cases it has been argued that the doctrine ought not to apply to a claimant involved in amateur sport as they are not engaged
‘in trade’. This argument must be accepted, as was illustrated in the Australian case Skelton v Australian Rugby Union Ltd,37 where an amateur sportsperson complains that they are prevented from competing as an amateur. However a fine distinction needs to be drawn where an amateur sportsperson is restricted from embarking on a professional career because of a restraint which limits his or her ability to follow their chosen occupation. North P (for the majority) in Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) appropriately held that an amateur player was
‘in trade’ in circumstances where they were refused clearance to
play professional rugby league in Australia.38 His Honour stated
that:
as a matter of principle, I can see no reason why the Court should be
powerless to intervene in appropriate cases where
a body
administering an amateur sport takes to itself the power to prevent its players
from seeking employment overseas as professional
footballers without its
consent.39
It is submitted that this expansive approach adopted by North P is correct.
The doctrine ought not to apply restrictively to professional
sportspersons.
This can be justified on the basis that there is often a
35 M McDonagh, ‘Restrictive Provisions in Players Agreements’ (1991) 4 Australian Journal of Labour Law 126, 133. See also Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353.
36 Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 371-372; Hughes v Western Australian Cricket
Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660; Barnard v Australian Soccer Federation (1988) 81 ALR 51;
Avellino v All Australia Netball Association Ltd [2004] SASC 56, [93].
37 [2002] QSC 193, [12]. The court will need to determine that the reality of the situation is that the player participates for pleasure, not money.
38 [1968] NZLR 547. See also: the Australian case Hall v Victorian Football League [1982] VicRp 6; [1982] VR 64 where an amateur footballer was considered to be ‘in trade’ in circumstances where he wished to embark upon a professional career but was limited by the governing body’s rules from doing so; Barnard v Australian Soccer Federation (1988) 81 ALR 51; and the English case Gasser v Stinson (Unreported, High Court Chancery, No Ch-88-G-2191, Scott J, 15 June 1988).
39 Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc)
[1968] NZLR 547, 545.
blurring of distinction between amateur and professional sport40
and/or a real potential for a budding sportsperson to earn a living from
the sport.41 There are many ‘amateurs’ whose livelihoods
would be affected if they were restricted from a sport or competition.
For instance, it is possible that a restriction would impact on an amateur
sportspersons reputation and therefore on his or her
ability to continue to earn
significant indirect financial reward through media contracts, sponsorship, or
the like.42
(b) Does the obligation ‘restrain’ the claimant in his or her
trade?
The second aspect which the claimant may be required to establish is that the obligation acts as a restraint on their trade. It is not necessary for a restraint to be absolute; it can be partial.43 A restraint of trade can take various forms, the most obvious being when access to a particular sport or competition is denied (whether temporarily or permanently).44
Other common restraints include labour market controls (such as
transfer systems, internal player-draft schemes, zoning and residential
rules, salary caps)45 and specific contractual terms contained in
player agreements.46
Often a restraint will be self evident with counsel agreeing from the outset that the particular obligation constitutes a restraint of trade.47
Nevertheless on occasion the courts will be required to analyse the nature
and extent of an obligation to determine if the claimant’s
ability
40 M McDonagh, ‘Restrictive Provisions in Players Agreements’ (1991) 4 Australian Journal of Labour Law 126, 133.
41 For example see:Hall v Victorian Football League [1982] VicRp 6; [1982] VR 64; Hughes v Western Australian
Cricket Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660, 700.
42 Hughes v Western Australian Cricket Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660, 700. See also: Stininato v Auckland Boxing Association (Inc) [1978] 1 NZLR 1, 12 (per Woodhouse J); and Gasser v Stinson (Unreported, High Court Chancery, No Ch-88-G-2191, Scott J, 15 June
1988).
43 A Lewis & J Taylor, Sport: Law and Practice (2003). For example see:Stevenage Borough
Football Club v Football League Ltd (1996) 9 Admin LR 109; Greig v Insole [1978] 3 All ER
449.
44 See Part C (1) of this article.
45 See below, n 83-87.
46 See below, n 88.
47 For example see: Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League
Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463; Wickham v Canberra District Rugby League Football
Club Ltd [1998] SCACT 9, [49]; Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991)
103 ALR 319.
to seek and engage in employment has been fettered. The courts have indicated
that when a governing body’s rules are under challenge,
these have to be
read in context with the nature of the game and with the body’s
constitution. “They are not to be read
like a contract wholly reduced to
writing”.48 This must be the correct approach as it enables
the court to practically49 consider whether there is
a restraint. The restraint also need not operate on trade within the courts
jurisdiction. The majority
in Blackler held that “any restraint on
employment whatsoever, whether it is intended to operate in New Zealand, or only
overseas, or both,
is prima facie void”.50
2. Is the restraint justified – is it reasonable?
On the claimant making out that there is a valid restraint of trade, the onus
will switch to the defendant (the sports governing body)
to prove on the
balance of probabilities that the restraint is reasonable and justified in
the interests of the parties. If the defendant can establish this, the
onus reverts back to the claimant who has the opportunity to prove that the
restraint is
not reasonable in the interests of the public. This is a
question of law for the courts.51 If the restraint is
contained in a contract the reasonableness of the restraint is to be assessed
at the time the contract was
entered into. Similarly, the validity of rules is
tested at the date of imposition.52
(a) Is the restraint reasonable having regard to the interests of the parties?
What is reasonable in the interests of the parties is the first limb of Lord
Macnaghten’s reasonableness test. A restraint of
trade will be void unless
the governing body can show that firstly, the restraint is reasonably
necessary to protect their interests (or objectives) and secondly, that
the restraint does not impose on the claimant a greater degree of restraint than
such reasonable
48 Wickham v Canberra District Rugby League Football Club Ltd [1998] SCACT 9, [55].
49 See: Goutzioulos v Victorian Soccer Federation Inc [2004] VSC 173, [18]; Avellino v All
Australia Netball Association Ltd [2004] SASC 56, [84]; Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd
[1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 345; Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 370.
50 Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547, 554-555 (per North
P) and 569 (per McCarthy J).
51 Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 377.
52 Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 359 (per Gummow J) and 346
(per Wilcox J).
protection requires.53 Typically this constitutes the
substantive issues for the courts in determining whether any obligation is an
unreasonable restraint
of trade.
Inherent in the first issue is the necessity for the sports governing
body to identify a legitimate interest requiring the court’s protection. A
legitimate
interest lies at the heart of the justification of restraint of trade
for if there are no interests worth protecting then the restraint
in question
will be unreasonable.54 This task of identifying a legitimate
interest can be difficult as sports governing bodies’ constituent
documents55 and policy statements usually deal with welfare
generalities not specific objectives in a “strict legal
sense”.56
Despite this, although it has sometimes been assumed,57 the
courts have recognised that sports bodies do have interests deserving of
protection which would justify a reasonable restraint.
This has included
interests which: achieve a competitive balance between clubs to maximise
spectator appeal (sporting equality),58 ensure a club’s
continued existence,59 protect the economic viability of a game or
competition and protect its proper organisation and
administration,60
53 See: Nordenfelt v Maxim Nordenfelt Guns and Ammunition Co Ltd [1894] UKLawRpAC 52; [1894] AC 535, 565; Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 377-378. Note that in Stevenage Borough Football Club v Football League Ltd (1996) 9 Admin LR 109 Carnwath J claimed that the standard of unreasonableness should be the public law Wednesbury standard due to the nature of a sports body. This was a marked departure from Nordenfelt.
54 J Carter & D Harland, Contract Law in Australia, (4th ed, 2002), 588 in C Davies, ‘The Use of Salary Caps in Professional Team Sports and the Restraint of Trade Doctrine’ (2006) 22 Journal of Contract Law 246, 247.
55 Most sports governing bodies in New Zealand are incorporated under the
Incorporated Societies Act 1908.Section 6(1)(b) requires the rules of the society to state the objects for which the society is established.
56 B Ward, ‘Fair Play: Professional Sport and Restraint of Trade’ (1985) 59 Law Institute
Journal 545, 546.See also dicta per Slade J in Greig v Insole [1978] 3 All ER 449, 496.
57 See Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547, 556 (per North
P).
58 This is usually the justification offered when restrictions limit the ability of players to move and in respect of rules which require transfer fees, drafts, and salary caps. For example see: Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 377; Foschini v Victoria Football League (Unreported, Supreme Court of Victoria, 9868/82, Crockett J, 15 April 1983); Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319.
59 Beetson v Humphries (Unreported, Supreme Court of NSW, No 10950, Hunt J, 30 May
1980); Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319.
60 Greig v Insole [1978] 3 All ER 449; Hoszowski v Brown (Unreported, Supreme Court of
NSW, No 1667/78, Helsham CJ, 6 October 1968); Eastham v Newcastle United
Football Club
aim to encourage new entrants,61 maintain the strength of the
game,62 and ensure a workable and deterrent system to improve the
quality of players from which the national team can be
selected.63
Assuming a legitimate interest has been identified, the restraint
imposed by the governing body must be reasonably related,
in that it advances or
protects that interest. It must not be inconsistent with it. This will depend
entirely on the evidence adduced
in each case. For example, in the recent
Australian case Avellino v All Australia Netball Association Ltd64
the Supreme Court of South Australia held that a residency rule for
players was inconsistent with one of the legitimate objectives
of the National
Netball League to “produce an ongoing, strong, dynamic
“national” competition”. The rule
did not advance
Avellino’s position. To the contrary it would “appear to restrict
players worthy of selection... from
being selected” in a national
competition.65
The second issue, namely whether the restraint has gone beyond that
which is considered reasonably necessary to protect the governing bodies
legitimate interest, has received far more attention. Ultimately, this issue
must be adjudged in light of the circumstances
of the particular case.
As Part C of this article will consider the reasonableness of specific types of
restraints, it is desirable
at this point to simply outline some general
principles which the courts may apply.
An initial factor which may be relevant is the bargaining power of the
parties. Specifically, the courts have indicated that a restraint
of trade
contained in a governing body’s constitution or rules will be treated
differently from a negotiated contractual restraint.66 The
distinguishing feature is that restraints in a sports body’s rules are
involuntarily imposed; there is no realistic opportunity
for the claimant to
negotiate. In contrast, there may be an opportunity to negotiate contractual
restraints. Thus if a contractual
agreement is reached through
fair
61 Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 9; (1991) 100 ALR 479.
62 Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463, 468-469.
63 Gasser v Stinson (Unreported, High Court Chancery, No Ch-88-G-2191, Scott J, 15 June
1988); Johnson v Athletics Canada (1997) 41 OTC 95.
65 Ibid [107].
66 Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463. See also Goutzioulos v
Victorian Soccer Federation Inc [2004] VSC 173.
bargaining, the courts justifiably are more likely to hold the restraint as
reasonable between the parties.67
In determining whether the restraint goes beyond that which is reasonable it
is necessary to analyse how wide or onerous
the restriction is (for
example, the duration of the restraint may be an important consideration). In
doing this it is the restraint
that must be looked at, not the way in which the
restraint is applied or intended to apply.68 Two questions may be of
significant influence here: is there any evidence that the legitimate interests
or objective of the governing
body might be jeopardised if the restraint was not
so drastic,69 and could the legitimate interests be met through a
less restrictive alternative means?70
Although Wilcox J in Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd71held
that the primary question will always be the extent of a governing body’s
need for protection, it is inevitable that the
court will also consider the
effect (or potential effect) of the restraint upon the claimant. The
harm caused to the affected
party must not be out of proportion to the benefit
secured by the sports governing body.72 While the case law has
unequivocally established that economic effects are relevant considerations, it
is not yet clear whether non-economic
considerations (such as the effects on
one’s personal life) will be relevant.73 A
67 For support of this proposition see dicta per Gummow J in Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 363. His Honour also asserts that if the restraint is involuntarily imposed, that there should be a heavier burden on the governing body to prove that the obligation should be enforceable. See also: Hawthorn Football Club v Harding [1988] VicRp 5; [1988] VR 39; Bulldogs Rugby League Club Ltd v Williams [2008] NSWSC 822, [46]-[47]; and A Humphreys, ‘Sport, Restraint of Trade and the Australian Courts: Adamson v New South Wales Rugby League Ltd’ [1993] SydLawRw 5; (1993) 15 Sydney Law Review 92, 97.
68 Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463. See also Adamson v
NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 360.
69 Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353; Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd (1991) 103 ALR
319.
70 Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 349-350.
71 Ibid 341 (per Wilcox J) and 323 (per Sheppard J). Sheppard J agreed that the Court must have regard to the effects of the restriction on the sportsperson in question but considered that there may be cases in which the restraint is so “obviously unreasonable” (or drastic) that no examination of its effect is required in order to reach a conclusion.
72 A Lewis & J Taylor, Sport: Law and Practice (2003), 175.
73 Wilcox J in Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 341 held that “non-
economic effects ought not to be disregarded. They may not be as easy to
evaluate as economic effects but they may be just as significant,
especially in
the case of a restraint on a person’s ability to choose an
employer.” In contrast Sheppard J (at 323) was
Humphreys convincingly argues that the whole argument of economic and
non-economic effects, not only being a difficult distinction
to maintain,
seems to overlook the foundations of the restraint of trade doctrine.74
The doctrine is essentially aimed at interferences with an
individual’s liberty of action. It is not based on any economic theory.
Therefore it is completely justifiable, in this sense, for the doctrine to be
concerned with wholly non-economic interests.
The courts, in deciding if a restraint of trade is unreasonable in the
circumstances, have commonly favoured an approach of balancing
the legitimate
interests of the governing body on the one hand against the interests of the
sportsperson on the other. Wilcox J succinctly
stated that:
[t]he very notion of reasonableness involves a balancing of competing
considerations. The more onerous the restraint, the more difficult it is for
the person seeking to enforce the restraint to satisfy a court that
it was, in
all of the circumstances, no more than was reasonably necessary for
the protection of his or her interests.75 [Emphasis
added]
So if, for example, the restraint imposed was onerous, it would be difficult
for the governing body to establish that the restraint
was reasonable. The
effect of the restraint on the claimant would have to be very minimal for the
court to be able to conclude that
the restraint was reasonable. However this
approach was criticised by Gummow J in Adamson. His Honour asserted that
while it was necessary to consider the position of the claimant the court is
“not to undertake a
balancing exercise with a comparative evaluation of
the weight of the interests of organisers and players”.76 To
do this, his Honour stated, would be to impermissibly lighten the burden of
proof carried by the governing body.77 Miles CJ in Wickham v
Canberra District Rugby League Football Club
undecided whether it was appropriate to take into account non-economic considerations.
74 A Humphreys, ‘Sport, Restraint of Trade and the Australian Courts: Adamson v New
South Wales Rugby League Ltd’ [1993] SydLawRw 5; (1993) 15 Sydney Law Review 92, 97-98.
75 Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 341. See also Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463, 469-470 where the Court approved of the balancing approach.
76 Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319, 364.
77 Ibid 365.
Ltd78 seemed to favour this approach. While there
is no recent authority in New Zealand as yet, it is in the interests of the
claimant
to argue that Gummow J’s approach ought to be adopted.
(b) Is the restraint reasonable having regard to the interests of the public?
Secondly if the governing body can establish that the restraint is reasonable
and justified in the interests of the parties, the claimant
has one final
opportunity to assert that the restraint is unreasonable in that it is
inconsistent with or reasonably injurious to
the public. This second limb of
Lord Macnaghten’s reasonableness test is not often considered by the
courts as the governing
body, in the majority of cases, is unable to make out
the first limb.79 Furthermore, A Buti correctly recognises that
another reason why public interest factors have received less attention is
because
they are intimately connected with the determination of what
is reasonable between the parties.80
Nevertheless the courts have on limited occasion cast their attention to
various public interest or policy considerations
when assessing
restraints. The High Court of Australia in Buckley v Tutty observed that
“it is contrary to the public welfare ... that the public should
unreasonably be deprived of the services of a
man prepared to engage in
employment”.81Therefore it is not in the
public’s interest to be denied access to the pleasure of watching players
of the highest skill
play at representative level.82 Even
still, it will be very rare for a restraint that is reasonable between
the parties to be invalidated specifically for
the reason that it is injurious
to the public.
78 [1998] SCACT 9, [49].
79 For example see: Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547,
572 (per McCarthy J); Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463;
Avellino v All Australia Netball Association Ltd [2004] SASC 56, [115].
80 A Buti, ‘Salary Caps in Professional Team Sports: An Unreasonable Restraint of Trade’ (1999) 14 Journal of Contract Law 130, 152.
81 [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353, 380.
82 See: Daley v New South Wales Rugby League Ltd (1995) 78 IR 247; Greig v Insole [1978] 3
All ER 449, 503; Hughes v Western Australian Cricket Association (Inc) (1986) 69 ALR 660,
703, where Toohey J held that it is in the public’s interest “in having every opportunity to
see first class cricketers in action”.
C. Application of the Restraint of Trade Doctrine: Denial of Access to a Sport or Competition
Now that the legal framework of the restraint of trade doctrine has been
established, this article will turn to specific circumstances
in which a
claimant may be able to call upon the doctrine to hold a sports governing body
to account. In doing this reference will
be made to several contemporary
situations in which a claim, if brought before the courts, could possibly
succeed.
There are broadly three established categories of restraint of trade
cases. Firstly, where a claimant is denied access
to a sport or
competition. Secondly, challenging a governing body’s labour market
controls (such as transfer rules within
a league,83 transfer rules
outside of a league,84 internal draft schemes,85 zoning
and residential rules,86 and salary caps).87 And thirdly,
specific contractual terms contained in player agreements which act as a
restraint.88 Due to recent interest in the former category and
extensive analysis of the latter categories,
83 For example see: Eastham v Newcastle United Football Club Ltd [1963] 3 All ER 139; Buckley v Tutty [1971] HCA 71; (1971) 125 CLR 353; Foschini v Victorian Football League (Unreported, Supreme Court of Victoria, BC8300014, 15 April 1983).
84 For example see: Blackler v New Zealand Rugby Football League (Inc) [1968] NZLR 547;
Kemp v New Zealand Rugby Football League Inc [1989] NZHC 53; [1989] 3 NZLR 463.
85 For example see: Adamson v NSW Rugby League Ltd [1991] FCA 425; (1991) 103 ALR 319; W Pengilley,
‘Sporting Drafts and Restraint of Trade’ (1994) 10 Queensland University of Technology Law
Journal 89; W Pengilley, ‘Restraint of Trade and Antitrust: A Pigskin Review Post Super
League’ (1997) 6 Canterbury Law Review 610.
86 For example see: Hall v Victorian Football League [1982] VicRp 6; [1982] VR 64; Avellino v All Australia Netball Association Ltd [2004] SASC 56; Nobes v Australian Cricket Board (Unreported, Supreme Court of Victoria, BC9102902, Marks J, 16 December 1991).
87 See J Taylor & M Newton, ‘Salary Caps - the Legal Analysis’ (2003) 11 Sport and the Law
Journal 158. For differing opinions as to whether salary caps are an unreasonable restraint of trade see A Buti, ‘Salary Caps in Professional Team Sports: An Unreasonable Restraint of Trade’ (1999) 14 Journal of Contract Law 130 (who argues that salary caps are unreasonable) and C Davies, ‘The Use of Salary Caps in Professional Team Sports and
the Restraint of Trade Doctrine’ (2006) 22 Journal of Contract Law 246(who argues that salary caps are not unreasonable).
88 See M McDonagh, ‘Restrictive Provisions in Players
Agreements’ (1991) 4 Australian Journal of Labour Law 126. For
example ‘playing’, ‘media/marketing’, or
‘conduct’ provisions may be an unreasonable restraint
of trade. In
Beetson v Humphries (Unreported, Supreme Court of NSW, No 10950, David
Hunt J, 30 May 1980) an unreasonable restraint took the form of a prohibition on
the content of journalistic articles published by rugby players. This was
‘completely unnecessary for the protection of the
Leagues
interests’.
attention will solely be directed at the former. It is important to emphasise
that these categories are by no means exhaustive. As
the doctrine has
progressively developed on public policy values, there is nothing to prevent a
claimant applying the legal framework,
as outlined above, to obligations which
impose novel restraints on their trade.
A claimant can be disciplined and denied access to a sport or competition by
virtue of a governing body’s rules or more commonly
the decision of a
disciplinary committee or the governing body itself. Exclusion in the form of a
ban or suspension constitutes a
‘restraint’. Therefore, assuming the
claimant is ‘in trade’, the issue for the courts is to determine the
reasonableness of the restraint.
As mentioned briefly in the introduction, perhaps the most high profile
current situation which may constitute an unreasonable restraint of
trade is the stance adopted by various national cricket bodies (such as the
England and
Wales Cricket Board (ECB) and New Zealand Cricket (NZC)) who
threatened to exclude those players that participated in the rebel Twenty20
ICL
from playing all ICC sanctioned cricket matches under their authority. While
this will be of little concern to many of the rebel
league players who are in
the twilight of their cricketing careers,89 for others, especially
New Zealand cricketers Hamish Marshall and Shane Bond,90 this stance
constitutes a severe restriction on their ability to earn a living from playing
cricket full time. If this stance was
maintained, firstly, Marshall and Bond
would be unable to honour and benefit financially from United Kingdom county
cricket contracts,91 secondly, they would not be permitted to hold
contracts to play for
89 Namely New Zealand cricketers: Chris Cairns, Adam Parore, Nathan Astle, Chris
Harris and Craig McMillan.
90 Also Daryl Tuffey, Andre Adams and Lou Vincent may be adversely affected.
91 Marshall signed a four year county cricket contract with Gloucestershire in 2007. Bond
also signed for Hampshire for six weeks at the start of the season. Centrally contracted players require a ‘no-objection certificate’ from their national cricket board to compete overseas; non-contracted players do not need this. However the ECB (governing body of English Cricket which includes county cricket) under a clause in their rules, initially refused to register these players (and others, despite a no-objection certificate being obtained), preventing them from competing in the Country Cricket Competition, because of their involvement with the ICL. See: G Longley, ‘Bond Defies ECB Ruling for
County’ (2008) The Press Sport,
<http://www.stuff.co.nz/thepress/4472558a6429.html>
at 10 April 2008. their domestic State Championship teams in New Zealand, and thirdly, they
would not be selected to play for the Blackcaps.92 This situation has significant parallels with Kerry Packer’s
1977-1978 ‘unsanctioned’ World Series Cricket (WSC) competition.93
In similar fashion, the ICC declared that all WSC players would be banned
from playing test cricket unless they rescinded their WSC
contracts by a certain
date. The ICC also recommended that national governing bodies take
similar action in respect of
their domestic game. This consequently
prompted a resolution from the English Test and County Cricket Board (TCCB) that
it would
alter its rules to disqualify any player from county cricket that was
subject to the ICC’s test match ban. Three contracted
WSC players Tony
Greig, Michael Proctor, and John Snow sought to challenge the ICC and
TCCB that these rules constituted
an unreasonable restraint of trade. Slade J, in the ensuing case Greig v Insole,94 held that
the rules were unreasonable, ultra vires, and therefore void. His Honour
claimed that although the ICC and TCCB did have legitimate interests to
protect,95 neither the ICC or TCCB discharged the onus of showing
that the retrospective ban on contracted WSC players was reasonable and
justified.
Slade J in analysing the extent of the ICC’s need
for protection arrived at the conclusion that while the WSC presented
an
immediate threat to the finances of Australian cricket, there was no serious
threat to the other test playing nations.96 Indeed the WSC
competition could possibly even raise the profile and bring increased interest
and financial benefit to the sport
as a whole.97 In the long
term 92 The Blackcaps are New Zealand’s national cricket team; R
Boock, ‘NZ Cricket Bans Six Rebels’(2007) Sunday Star Times,
<http://www.stuff.co.nz/4340511a10133.html>
at 30 December 2007. 93 For a comprehensive overview of the WSC situation see: G Haigh,
Cricket War: The Inside Story of Packer’s World Series Cricket (1993). 95 Ibid 497. Namely, that it was in the public interest that
cricket should be properly organised and administered. 96 Ibid 501. It was argued that WSC was a grave threat to the
economic viability of the game. WSC would diminish the income derived from
test
cricket and threaten the game as a whole by reducing the profits which would be
passed either directly or indirectly to the lower levels of the game. The ICC therefore argued it was acting
reasonably in aiming to prevent players from taking part in the WSC competition which could
threaten the ICC’s legitimate interest. 97 Ibid. however, the WSC could present a threat to test playing countries. But this,
his Honour held, could have been adequately met by imposing
a prospective
disqualification on players who thereafter contracted with or played WSC.98
While a prospective ban would not necessarily be valid, Slade J
stated, it could be more easily justified than a retrospective ban which in this
case was both a ‘serious and unjust
step to take.’99 The
Court therefore held that the benefits derived from the ban were highly
speculative and did not outweigh the injustice
of depriving WSC players
of an important means of making their living. Furthermore the public would be
deprived of a great deal
of pleasure if they did not have the opportunity of
watching the WSC players in official test matches.100 Slade J
then went onto hold that the TCCB’s resolution to ban WSC players from
county cricket was even more serious and
therefore it was also an
unreasonable restraint.101 Likewise, in the subsequent case Hughes v Western Australian Cricket
Association (WACA) (Inc)102 the WACA sought to automatically
ban cricketers from playing in Australia who had participated, or intended to
participate in unauthorised
cricket matches in South Africa without their
written authority. Toohey J held that this rule went beyond a restraint
reasonably
related to the object of control and regulation of cricket in Western
Australia for the following reasons: the disqualification was
for an indefinite
time, the rule imposed automatic disqualification, there was no right to appeal
the ban, the rule precluded playing
cricket overseas, and the rule applied
retrospectively.103 The totality of these considerations lead to
Toohey J’s finding which was reinforced by the fact that the restraint was
contrary
to the public’s interest. With the ICL situation being virtually analogous to the circumstances of
Greig and also drawing on the authority in Hughes, it is submitted
that 98 Ibid. 99 Ibid 501 and 503. 100 Ibid 503. 101 Ibid 503-504. While test cricket presents a valuable
opportunity for cricketers to supplement their income from time to time by
playing
in test matches, county cricket offers an opportunity to earn a living
by playing full time cricket throughout the English summer.
The denial of the
opportunity to play in English county cricket is therefore a much more serious
deprivation to players. 103 Ibid 703. if national cricket bodies continue to maintain their stance in banning rebel
league players from participating in ICC sanctioned
events this is likely, if
challenged before a court, to constitute an unreasonable restraint of
trade. Even if a national
cricket body imposed a prospective ban this should
still be deemed unreasonable. Applying the commonly adopted balancing approach,
the effect on the players of such an onerous obligation (it is difficult to
think of a more onerous obligation) would outweigh any
possible legitimate
interest of the ban. On a ‘fair and objective basis’104
these players do not deserve such a sanction. It is no answer for the
governing body to say that they ‘might have expected it.’105
Additionally the public would be denied access to watch some of the most
talented players participate at the highest level in one-day
and test matches.
This would quite likely injure the sport. Merely by NZC (or another national cricket body) overlooking a player for
national selection (or as NZC officially stated ‘that
the selectors will
be encouraged to consider other players’ who have not played in the ICL)
rather than impose an outright
ban, does not avoid the issue.106 What is important is the practical effect of the restraint on the
players.107 However as most of the New Zealand rebel league players
have no desire or ambition to play for the Blackcaps again, perhaps of greater
concern for them was the stance initially adopted by the ECB in denying them
access from playing county cricket. Fortunately for
Bond and Marshall they did
not have to resort to challenging the legality of the ECB’s initial
position as the ECB eventually
softened their stance and granted these players
clearance.108 This was a sensible move from the ECB. Other situations associated with the ICL which may provoke cricketers to
bring a restraint of trade claim in the future include: if
a national cricket
body refuses to release centrally contracted players109
to 104 Greig v Insole [1978] 3 All ER 449, 503-504. 105 Ibid. 106 D Hopps, ‘Bond’s Choice of Indian League Opens a Legal
Can of Worms’(2008) The Guardian Sport
<http://sport.guardian.co.uk/cricket/story/ 0,,2233977,00.html>
at 2 January 2008. 107 See above, Part B (1)(b) of this article at n 49. 108 The Press, ‘English Officials Clear Bond, Marshall to
Play’ The Press (Christchurch) at 12 April 2008. 109 A clause in national cricket contracts usually states that the
national cricket body is to approve of any matches which the player plays in: The Press, ‘Bond Spat
has Parallels’ compete in the ICL when they are not required for their country110
(or even the rival ICC sanctioned Twenty20 Indian Premier League (IPL)
competition111); or if a national cricket body determines that it
will not select a centrally contracted cricketer for the national team because
of the fact that the cricketer has signed to play in the ICL at the
conclusion of their contract.112 While the first potential situation
may not be as likely to constitute an unreasonable restraint of trade
if the cricketer had the opportunity to negotiate their national contract
and it was reached through fair bargaining, the latter situation,
applying
Greig, could well be considered unreasonable. A claimant who is denied access to a sport or competition may also be able
to successfully apply the doctrine in several other
established factual
scenarios. The courts have held a restraint to be unreasonable where: a sports
governing body’s rules
were amended to impose a ban on sportspersons who
played another sport,113 a licence application was refused which was
necessary to compete in a particular sport,114 a governing
body’s rules excluded certain players from consideration for selection in
all representative matches,115 and where a winning sports The Press (Christchurch) at 19 January 2008. 110 R Boock, ‘Rebel, Rebel’ Sunday Star Times (NZ
National) at 2 March 2008. Note that Lou Vincent breached his NZC Contract when he signed and left to play for the
ICL without even seeking the permission of NZC. 111 See O Brett, ‘England IPL Ban ‘Will not
Work’’ (2008) BBC Sport,
<http://news.bbc.co.uk/sport2/hi/cricket/england/7338282.stm>
at 9 April 2008. The ECB’s present stance is to not allow centrally contracted English
cricket players to play in the sanctioned IPL. If the ECB
does not soften their
stance it is possible that a claim could be brought. Although this is possible,
it is very unlikely that the
players will challenge the ECB, as they would be
jeopardising their chances of being selected for England. 112 The Press, ‘Bond Spat has Parallels’, The Press
(Christchurch) at 19 January 2008. Shane Bond signed to play in the ICL in January 2008 at a time when he held a NZC
contract. This contract was due to expire in May 2008.
NZC did not wish to
select him for the Blackcaps because of his future ICL involvement. In the end,
Bond and NZC came to an arrangement
that he would be released early from his
contract and would not be selected for the Blackcaps. 113 Barnard v Australian Soccer Federation (1988) 81 ALR 51. Here
FIFA wished to not only control outdoor soccer but also indoor soccer. FIFA thereby amended its rules
so that any person who played indoor soccer (for the
rival governing body FIFUSA
or an affiliate of FIFUSA) was banned from playing outdoor soccer. 114 For example see:Nagle v Feilden [1966] 1 All ER 689;
Stininato v Auckland Boxing Association (Inc) [1978] 1 NZLR 1. Note the possibility of raising an
alternative action claiming that there is ‘a right to work’. 115 Daley v New South Wales Rugby League Ltd (1995) 78 IR
247. club was denied promotion in a League on the basis that it did not meet the
other admission criteria by a prescribed date.116 On the other hand, there have been certain situations where despite a
participant being denied access to a sport or competition there
has been a
degree of reluctance from the courts in finding the restraint to be
unreasonable. One situation is where a player is suspended
for foul
play.117 The important distinction here is that the player is
precluded by reason of his or her own past misconduct rather than by general
regulation. The object of a suspension is to deter violence or other
misbehaviour by players and to protect the reputation of the
sport. The
restriction on the claimant’s freedom is merely incidental.118
Therefore the courts have indicated that they will apply a similar
standard as to the reasonableness of a suspension as is commonly
found in a
judicial review action. That is, that the suspension, at the least, must be
unreasonable of a kind that no reasonable
tribunal could have made such a
decision.119 Another situation where the courts have shown reluctance is in relation to
athletes that are suspended from a sport by virtue of committing
a doping
offence. In Gasser v Stinson120 the English High Court held
that although strict liability drug rules which imposed automatic blanket
suspensions on athletes found
to have prohibited substances in their body was
a restraint of trade, this rule was proportionate and reasonable not
only
in the interests of the parties but also the public.121 There is a need to eliminate and deter drug taking in sport. To permit an
athlete to endeavour to establish their ‘moral innocence’
in such
a 116 Stevenage Borough Football Club v Football League Ltd
(1996) 9 Admin LR 109. Although Stevenage Borough finished top of the GM
Vauxhall Conference they were denied promotion in the League on the grounds that
it did not satisfy certain requirements relating to ground capacity and safety
by December of the winning season. It would however,
have been able to satisfy
these requirements by the start of the new season. Carnwath J, stated
(obiterdicta), that this entry criterion was an unreasonable restraint of
trade. A discretionary remedy was not granted though. 117 Skelton v Australian Rugby Union Ltd [2002] QSC
193. 118 Ibid [13]. 119 See above, n 53; See also Jackson v Western Australia Basketball
Federation Inc (1990) 21 ADL 283, 288 applying Shepherd v South Australian Amateur Football League
Inc (1987) 44 SASR 579, 586 (per Cox J). 120 (Unreported, High Court Chancery, No Ch-88-G-2191, Scott J, 15
June 1988); see also Wilander v Tobin [1997] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 195. 121 A Lewis & J Taylor, Sport: Law and Practice
(2003). situation would be difficult to prove and lead to an opening of the
floodgates.122 However in contrast, there is greater potential for a claimant to attack the
length of a doping suspension for being unreasonable.123 This is
especially so in relation to a four-year or life ban from a sport, but even a
two-year suspension may be an unreasonable restraint
of trade in some
circumstances.124 This fear of challenge prompted the
International Association of Athletics Federation (IAAF) in 1997 to halve the
mandatory
length of suspension to two years.125 The new World
Anti-Doping Code (WADC), effective as from 1 January 2009, may come under
challenge in this respect as sanctions have
been toughened to impose four-year
bans for a greater number of offences. As outlined in the introduction, a sports governing body’s rule (such
as BOA byelaw 25) which imposes a lifetime ban on sportspersons
found guilty of
a doping offence from competing in a particular competition (such as the
Olympics), could well, and it is
submitted should, constitute an
unreasonable restraint of trade. The Olympics is the pinnacle event for any
athlete. To be banned
for life from competing in 122 Gasser v Stinson (Unreported, High Court Chancery, No
Ch-88-G-2191, Scott J, 15 June 1988). For more detailed commentary see: A Greenhow,
‘Anti-Doping Suspensions and Restraint of Trade in Sport’ (2008) Sports Law eJournal,
<http://epublications.bond.edu.au/slej/7>
A Mathieson, ‘The World Anti-Doping Agency and the World Anti-Doping Code: Can the Right of an Athlete to Compete
Freely and the Right of Sport to Regulate Competition
be Reconciled?’
(2006) 65 The Commentator 3; and T Buti & S Fridman, ‘Drug
Testing in Sport: Legal Challenges and Issues’ [1999] UQLawJl 1; (1998-1999) 20
University of Queensland Law Journal 153. Note that the new WADC (2009)
provides greater flexibility to reduce sanctions from zero to two years for
specified substances (lesser
offences) where an athlete can establish there is
no intention to enhance performance. This undermines the previous strict liability position:
Yahoo, ‘Athletics Stays Tough in the Face of Softer
Sanctions’(2007) Yahoo UK and Ireland Sport,
<http://uk.eurosport.yahoo.com/16112007/3/athletics-stays-tough-face-softer- sanctions.html>
at 16 November 2007. 123 See T Buti & S Fridman, ‘Drug Testing in Sport:
Legal Challenges and Issues’ (1998- [1999] UQLawJl 1; 1999) 20 University of Queensland Law Journal 153. 124 See Robertson v Australian Professional Cycling
Council Inc (Unreported, Supreme Court of NSW, Waddell CJ, 10 September
1993). Also in May 1997 Katrin Krabbe was awarded damages by the German
Athletics Federation after a German Court determined that a three year
suspension was an unreasonable restraint of trade. 125 Yahoo, ‘Athletics Stays Tough in the Face of Softer
Sanctions’(2007) Yahoo UK and Ireland Sport,
<http://uk.eurosport.yahoo.com/16112007/3/athletics-stays-tough-face- softer-sanctions.html>
at 16 November 2007. such an event for an offence already served seems excessive and unjust. It
places on the claimant a greater degree of restraint than
such reasonable
protection requires. It is extremely difficult to view that the BOA’s
legitimate interests in this rule (presumably
to deter drug taking and to
protect the country’s reputation) would outweigh the economic and
non-economic effects on an affected
sportsperson. Further, it is quite possible
that the legitimate interests of the BOA could be met through a less restrictive
route,
such as by providing a rule that drug offenders must not compete in the
Olympics for a ‘four-year Olympic cycle.’126 A convincing
argument could also be submitted that a ban of this nature would deny the
public access to the pleasure of
ever watching the banned athlete compete
at the Olympics. Conclusion It is no exaggeration that restraint of trade, as a mechanism for challenge,
is an extremely “powerful weapon”.127 As illustrated,
the doctrine is highly accessible, flexible, and can apply to a broad
spectrum of circumstances which unreasonably
limit a player’s,
club’s, or other participant’s ability to earn a living. In this
professional age of sport in
which governing bodies are increasingly
exercising greater control over the actions of participants, it is important
for interested
parties to be aware of the limits to this and the legal
principles that will be applied upon bringing a challenge. A ‘red’
or ‘yellow’ card shown by a governing body to limit the actions of a
participant need not always be accepted, and if
challenged before a court of
law, may well be deemed
unenforceable. 126 This is the approach of the New Zealand Olympic Committee
(NZOC). For example see The Herald, ‘Cycling: Drugs Ban Comes Back
to
Haunt Yates’ (2008) The Herald News,
<http://www.nzherald.co.nz/topic/story.cfm ?c_id=500833 & objectid=10504615>
at 17 April 2007. 127 P Morris & G Little, “Challenging Sports Bodies”
Determinations’ (1998) 17 Civil Justice Quarterly 128, 140.
NZLII:
Copyright Policy
|
Disclaimers
|
Privacy Policy
|
Feedback
URL: http://www.nzlii.org/nz/journals/NZLawStuJl/2009/4.html